Photo: Todd Niemand |
In the June
addendum to the FOMC’s statement, the Federal Reserve came awfully close to
admitting it doesn’t know how big its balance sheet should be.
The ultimate size would be “appreciably below” the current level,
but “larger than” before the crisis, yielding a figure somewhere between $900
billion and $4.5 trillion, with the final decision reflecting reserves demand
and whatever the FOMC thinks is optimal for implementing policy. “The Committee
expects to learn more about the underlying demand for reserves during the
process of balance sheet normalisation,” it said.
Though the Fed is perfectly able to set interest rates with
asset holdings at either end of that range, it bears thinking about what the
ideal size is.
Central banks set the short-term interest rate by
controlling the interaction of liquidity and rates in the financial system. When
a commercial bank has excess liquidity at the end of the day it can either lend
it overnight to another bank or deposit it at the central bank, and the
abundance or otherwise of spare cash in the system sets the price (the
interbank rate). With demand for liquidity satiated by the quantitative easing
firehose, most of the surplus cash ends up at the central bank and the
interbank rate becomes pinned at the central bank’s deposit rate.
Fine. No big problem – for instance, post-QE the Bank of
England put the old corridor system on hold and just said the policy rate and
the deposit rate were the same thing. The Fed is using a slightly more
complicated blend of interest on excess reserves and overnight reverse repos to
achieve a similar effect. But what should be the approach in ‘normal’ times?
The Fed may be hinting with its “underlying demand” comment
that it’s considering trying to keep the system satiated, but only just. That
is achievable, for instance with a process of trial and error – keep shrinking
the balance sheet until interbank rates start to show signs of life and then
stop. You can always use open market operations to pin rates back down if they
try to escape.
Why keep the system satiated? One answer is offered by Robin
Greenwood, Samuel Hanson and (former Fed governor) Jeremy Stein in their 2016 Jackson
Hole paper. They argue the Fed can muscle in on the short-term liability
issuing game by forcing banks to hold lots of reserves. The thinking is this
promotes stability by curbing excessive maturity transformation and keeping the
system nice and liquid.
Greenwood, Hanson and Stein recommend keeping the balance
sheet at $4.5 trillion, which the Fed is clearly not keen to do. So why shrink
it? Because there are risks to size: as the short term interest rate rises, the
Fed may eventually start paying out more to banks in interest than it earns
from seigniorage. Of course, a central bank theoretically can’t be insolvent,
but you can see why the Fed wouldn’t be super keen to go cap in hand to the
Trump administration, especially for several years in a row.
Charles Goodhart, in a recent
paper for the Central Banking journal,
points out that while liquidity satiation is desirable from the perspective of
financial stability, normal liquidity demand can very quickly switch to (much
higher) crisis demand. Instead of having to relaunch QE every time the banking
sector wobbles, central banks could employ a system of contingent,
pre-positioned collateral, allowing banks to very quickly boost their liquidity
in a panic. This is Mervyn King’s “pawnbroker
for all seasons” idea.
The pawnbroker idea has the significant advantage of
efficiency – not only freeing up bank assets, but creating informational
efficiencies too, à la Bengt Holmström, who likewise uses the pawnbroker analogy. If
everyone is confident there is plenty of collateral (and therefore liquidity)
available, the system runs less risk of seizing up in the first place.
Goodhart would like to see the system returned more or less
to its pre-crisis set-up, with a corridor for setting short-term rates, a small
quantity of reserves, and a “vastly increased” pre-positioning framework for
obtaining liquidity under stress.
The New York Fed’s Simon Potter made it clear in a speech on
November 6 that FOMC policymakers are yet to decide whether they want a “reserve-abundant”
or “reserve-scarce” system. As they come to choose, they would do well to
consider Goodhart’s suggestion.
No comments:
Post a Comment